Saturday, May 10, 2014

The Student Loan Issue Looks Clear Enough At First Glance:

By Ester Brown


Students are incurring oversized student debt, and they are defaulting on that debt and threatening their ability to access future credit. The approaches to student loan debt collection are fraught with problems, including improper recovery tactics and informational asymmetry regarding repayment options.

But the current public policy conversations miss key issues that contribute to the debt mess, leading to proffered solutions that also miss their mark.

Start with these essential details about student loans:

Averages are represented by the noted student debt loans, however the sums owed can differ radically from student to student. That is the reason why the problems are not resolved by options such as the mandated debt calculator on school sites or the present School Scorecard; the revealing of universal info will not influence pupil option meaningfully.

Another View on Loans

The right level of default for a school's grads and student loan debt depends heavily on mission and an institution's students, compose Jacob Gross and Nicholas Hillman.

Many of the problematic student loans are held by individuals who left college before graduation, meaning they have incurred "debt without diploma." This reality distorts default statistics, making their indication of school quality misleading. The cost of education is not necessarily commensurate with the quality of the education received, meaning some students pay more and get less, and we do not have an adequate system for measuring educational quality other than accreditation, which is a deeply flawed process.

Finally, students and their families are woefully unaware of the myriad repayment options, and therefore forgo existing benefits or are taken advantage of by loan services. This occurs because we de-link conversations of "front-end" costs of higher education from "back-end" repayment options and opportunities; students and their families are scared off by the front end without knowing that there is meaningful back-end relief.

Given these facts, it becomes clearer why several of the existing government reform suggestions are misguided. Two illustrations:

First, assessing universities on a ranking system depending on the making degrees of the alumnae supposes the overwhelming bulk of pupils grad and the occupation selected is going to be large-spending. But we realize that perhaps not to be accurate, as well as for great reason: some pupils proudly enter public-service or another low-spending but openly valuable employment. And, in to day's market, not absolutely all pupils may locate job directly correlated to their own field of research.

We also know that those from high-income families have greater networking opportunities, given family connections. Yes, some schools offer degrees with little or no value, but the solution to student loan indebtedness does not rest on an earnings threshold.

Second, seeking at loan default charges as a measure of the achievement of a faculty misses that numerous faculties welcome students from low income quartiles, although obviously many are working to improve these figures, and these students have less collegiate success -- understandably.

Not that many years ago, private lenders dominated both the student lending and home mortgage markets. This created obvious parallels between lending in these two spheres. Lenders overpriced for risk, provided monies to borrowers who were not credit-worthy, and had loan products with troubling features like sizable front-end fees, high default interest rates and aggressive debt collection practices.

In both markets, there was an embedded assumption: real estate values would continue to rise and well-paying employment opportunities would be plentiful for college graduates.

Afterward several things happened. The federal government took over the student loan market, cutting out the private lender as the middleman on government loans on the front and back end. The economy took a nose-dive that resulted in diminished dwelling values and lower occupations. And, when the proverbial bubble blast in the dwelling lending markets, lenders sought to foreclose, only to find that their collateral had declined in value.

For student education loans, the bubble has not explode and, despite hyperbole to the opposite, it's not likely to explode as the authorities -- maybe not the private-sector -- is the lender. Truly, this marketplace is purposefully not centered on credit worthiness; more dollars are awarded by it to those with poor credit, particularly to empower educational chance, if something.

And while Congress can debate the interest rates charged on student loans, the size of Pell Grants and the growing default rates, it is highly improbable that the student loan market will be privatized any time soon.

But, for the document, there are already hints that private lenders and venture capitalists have reentered or are prepared to reenter this market, for better or worse. And should the us government's financial aid offerings are or become less favorable than those in the open marketplace, we are going to visit a resurrection of private lending offered to students and their loved ones. One caveat: history tells us that the threats of the private student loan market are large.

There are things that can and should be done to improve the government-run student-lending market to encourage our most vulnerable students to pursue higher education at institutions that will serve them well. Here are five timely and doable suggestions worth considering now:

Lower the interest rates on government-issued subsidized Stafford loans. Student loans to our most financially risky students should remain without regard to credit worthiness. Otherwise, we will be left with educational opportunity available only for the rich.

And the government has not been sufficiently proactive in recognizing creditors, despite clear ability to do so.

(3) Simplify (as was completed successfully using the FAFSA) the re-payment choices. There are a lot of choices and too many chances for pupils to err within their choice. We are aware that income-based repayment is under-utilized, and pupils become ostriches rather than unraveling and working through the choices truly accessible. Mandated exit interviews are not a "teachable moment" for this info; we need to tell pupils more smartly. Thought needs to be given to advice in the time re-payment kicks in --- typically half a year post-graduation.

(4) Encourage college and universities to work on post-graduation default rates (and repayment options) by establishing programs where they (the educational institutions) pro-actively reach out to their graduates to address repayment options, an initiative we will be trying on our own campus. Improvement in institutional default rates could be structured to enable increased institutional access to federal monies for work-study or SEOG, the greater the improvement, the greater the increase.

The suggestion, then, is contrary to the proffered government approach: taking away advantages.

Create a new financial product for parents/guardians/family members/friends who want to borrow to assist their children (or those whom they are raising or supporting even if not biological or step children) in progressing through higher education, replacing the current Parent Plus Loan.

Home ownership and education are both part of the American dream. We need to stop shouting about the shared crisis and see how we can truly help students and their families access higher education rather than making them run for the proverbial hills.




About the Author:



No comments:

Post a Comment